Iron Law Of Prohibition
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

The iron law of prohibition is a term coined by Richard Cowan in 1986 which posits that as law enforcement becomes more intense, the potency of prohibited substances increases. Cowan put it this way: "the harder the enforcement, the harder the drugs." This law is an application of the
Alchian–Allen effect The Alchian–Allen effect was described in 1964 by Armen Alchian and William R Allen in the book ''University Economics'' (now called ''Exchange and Production''). It states that when the prices of two substitute goods, such as high and low grade ...
;
Libertarian Libertarianism (from french: libertaire, "libertarian"; from la, libertas, "freedom") is a political philosophy that upholds liberty as a core value. Libertarians seek to maximize autonomy and political freedom, and minimize the state's e ...
judge Jim Gray calls the law the "cardinal rule of prohibition", and notes that is a powerful argument for the
legalization of drugs Drug liberalization is a drug policy process of decriminalizing or legalizing the use or sale of prohibited drugs. Variations of drug liberalization include: drug legalization, drug re-legalization and drug decriminalization. Proponents of drug ...
. It is based on the premise that when drugs or alcohol are prohibited, they will be produced in
black market A black market, underground economy, or shadow economy is a clandestine market or series of transactions that has some aspect of illegality or is characterized by noncompliance with an institutional set of rules. If the rule defines the se ...
s in more concentrated and powerful forms, because these more potent forms offer better efficiency in the business model—they take up less space in storage, less weight in transportation, and they sell for more money. Economist
Mark Thornton Mark Thornton (born June 7, 1960) is an American economist of the Austrian School. DiLorenzo, Thomas (2011-02-11My Associations with Liars, Bigots, and Murderers ''LewRockwell.com'' He has written on the topic of prohibition of drugs, the econo ...
writes that the iron law of prohibition undermines the argument in favor of prohibition, because the higher potency forms are less safe for the consumer.


Findings

Thornton published research showing that the potency of marijuana increased in response to higher enforcement budgets. He later expanded this research in his dissertation to include other illegal drugs and alcohol during
Prohibition in the United States In the United States from 1920 to 1933, a Constitution of the United States, nationwide constitutional law prohibition, prohibited the production, importation, transportation, and sale of alcoholic beverages. The alcohol industry was curtai ...
(1920–1933). The basic approach is based on the Alchian and Allen Theorem. This argument says that a fixed cost (e.g. transportation fee) added to the price of two varieties of the same product (e.g. high quality red apple and a low quality red apple) results in greater sales of the more expensive variety. When applied to
rum-running Rum-running or bootlegging is the illegal business of smuggling alcoholic beverages where such transportation is forbidden by law. Smuggling usually takes place to circumvent taxation or prohibition laws within a particular jurisdiction. The ter ...
,
drug smuggling The illegal drug trade or drug trafficking is a global black market dedicated to the cultivation, manufacture, distribution and sale of drug prohibition, prohibited drugs. Most jurisdictions prohibitionism, prohibit trade, except under license, ...
, and
blockade running A blockade runner is a merchant vessel used for evading a naval blockade of a port or strait. It is usually light and fast, using stealth and speed rather than confronting the blockaders in order to break the blockade. Blockade runners usuall ...
the more potent products become the sole focus of the suppliers. Thornton notes that the greatest added cost in illegal sales is the avoidance of detection. Thornton says that if drugs are legalized, then consumers will begin to wean themselves off the higher potency forms, for instance with
cocaine Cocaine (from , from , ultimately from Quechuan languages, Quechua: ''kúka'') is a central nervous system (CNS) stimulant mainly recreational drug use, used recreationally for its euphoria, euphoric effects. It is primarily obtained from t ...
users buying
coca Coca is any of the four cultivated plants in the family Erythroxylaceae, native to western South America. Coca is known worldwide for its psychoactive alkaloid, cocaine. The plant is grown as a cash crop in the Argentine Northwest, Bolivia, Al ...
leaves, and
heroin Heroin, also known as diacetylmorphine and diamorphine among other names, is a potent opioid mainly used as a recreational drug for its euphoric effects. Medical grade diamorphine is used as a pure hydrochloride salt. Various white and brow ...
users switching to
opium Opium (or poppy tears, scientific name: ''Lachryma papaveris'') is dried latex obtained from the seed capsules of the opium poppy ''Papaver somniferum''. Approximately 12 percent of opium is made up of the analgesic alkaloid morphine, which i ...
. The popular shift from beer to wine to hard liquor during the US Prohibition era has a parallel in the narcotics trade in the late 20th century. Bulky opium was illegal, so refined heroin became more prevalent, albeit with significant risk from blood-borne disease because of injection by needle, and far greater risk of death from overdose. Marijuana was also found too bulky and troublesome to smuggle across borders, so smugglers turned to refined cocaine with its much higher potency and profit per pound. Cowan wrote in 1986 that
crack cocaine Crack cocaine, commonly known simply as crack, and also known as rock, is a free base form of the stimulant cocaine that can be smoked. Crack offers a short, intense high to smokers. The ''Manual of Adolescent Substance Abuse Treatment'' calls ...
was entirely a product of the prohibition of drugs. Clinical psychiatrist Michael J. Reznicek adds
crystal meth Methamphetamine (contracted from ) is a potent central nervous system (CNS) stimulant that is mainly used as a recreational drug and less commonly as a second-line treatment for attention deficit hyperactivity disorder and obesity. Methamphe ...
to this list. In the 2010s the iron law has been invoked to explain why heroin is displaced by
fentanyl Fentanyl, also spelled fentanil, is a very potent synthetic opioid used as a pain medication. Together with other drugs, fentanyl is used for anesthesia. It is also used illicitly as a recreational drug, sometimes mixed with heroin, cocaine ...
and other, even stronger, synthetic opioids. With underage drinking by teens in the U.S., one of the impacts of laws against possession of alcohol by minors is that teens tend to prefer distilled spirits, because they are easier to conceal than beer.


Derivation

Consider the situation where there are two substitute goods x_ and x_, denoting the higher and lower quality goods with respective prices p_ and p_, and where p_ > p_ i.e. the higher quality good has a higher price. Each of these goods has a compensated demand curve (a demand curve which holds utility constant) of the form x_ = h_(p_,p_,U), \quad i \in \, where \left(h_(p_,p_,U)\right)_ = h(p_,p_,U)) = \underset \, \sum_ p_i x_i, with u(x) denoting the utility function of the consumer. Furthermore, we will also assume that income is held constant, as
income effect The theory of consumer choice is the branch of microeconomics that relates preferences to consumption expenditures and to consumer demand curves. It analyzes how consumers maximize the desirability of their consumption as measured by their pref ...
s are indeterminate in forecasting changes in demand. Suppose that there is an associated cost \tau that is added to each good due to transport costs. We want to know how the ratio of demand x_/x_ changes for the two goods based on \tau. Taking the derivative with respect to \tau yields From our assumptions, we have that the total price for each item is p_ + \tau. Therefore, we may compute \partial x_/\partial \tau to be = + , \quad i \in \. We may now rewrite () as Finally, using the cross-
elasticity Elasticity often refers to: *Elasticity (physics), continuum mechanics of bodies that deform reversibly under stress Elasticity may also refer to: Information technology * Elasticity (data store), the flexibility of the data model and the cl ...
of demand, \epsilon_ = , \quad i,j \in \, we arrive at the following expression of the derivative Now, we want to show that \partial_(x_/x_) > 0, but seem to be stuck with elasticities that are indeterminate. However, Hicks' third law of demand gives us \epsilon_ = -\epsilon_ and \epsilon_ = -\epsilon_. To see why this is, suppose that we take a more general version of the compensated demand function with n goods and compensated demand curves h_(p_,\dots,p_,U), for i = 1,\dots,n. For a
homogeneous function In mathematics, a homogeneous function is a function of several variables such that, if all its arguments are multiplied by a scalar, then its value is multiplied by some power of this scalar, called the degree of homogeneity, or simply the ''deg ...
f(z_,\dots,z_,V) of degree m, defined as f(\lambda z_,\dots,\lambda z_,V) = \lambda^f(z_,\dots,z_,V),
Euler's homogeneous function theorem In mathematics, a homogeneous function is a function of several variables such that, if all its arguments are multiplied by a scalar, then its value is multiplied by some power of this scalar, called the degree of homogeneity, or simply the ''deg ...
states that m f(z_,\dots,z_,V) = z_ + \cdots + z_. Compensated demand functions are homogeneous of degree 0, since multiplying all prices by a constant \lambda > 0 yields the same solution to the
expenditure minimization problem In microeconomics, the expenditure minimization problem is the dual of the utility maximization problem: "how much money do I need to reach a certain level of happiness?". This question comes in two parts. Given a consumer's utility function, p ...
as the original prices. Thus, 0 = p_ + \cdots + p_, \quad i = 1,\dots,n . Dividing by the stock x_ yields 0 = + \cdots + = \sum_^\epsilon_, \quad i = 1,\dots,n, which establishes Hicks' third law of demand. Using Hicks' law, () is rewritten as Suppose for the sake of contradiction that \frac\left( \frac \right) \leq 0. Then, -(\epsilon_ + \epsilon_) + (\epsilon_ + \epsilon_) \leq 0 . By initial assumption, our two goods are substitutes. As such, \epsilon_ > 0 and \epsilon_ > 0, implying that -\frac + \frac \leq 0 \quad \Longleftrightarrow \quad p_L \geq p_H. But, this contradicts the assumption that p_H > p_L. Thus, we conclude that \frac\left( \frac \right) > 0. This implies that as the transport costs increase, the higher quality good will become more prevalent than the lower quality good. In the drug-specific context, as costs associated with drug enforcement increase, the more potent drug will become more prevalent in the illegal drug market.


References


Further reading

* * * * * {{refend Economics laws Prohibition 1986 in economics Drug control law Smuggling Law and economics Mathematical economics